Mito ekonomikoak: eskuin eta ezker berdin

Aukeratu dut Mitchell-en ondoko lana oso zabalduta (ezker eta eskuin!) dauden zenbait mito aipatu eta kritikatzearren. Afera ez dagokio, tamalez, soilik Australiari…

Bill Mitchell-en Don’t let neo-liberal (idiots) loose with a spreadsheet!1

(a) Sarrera: makroekonomia eta politika fiskala2

(b) Artikulua: The higher the government debt, the slower economic growth3

(c) Zorra eta hazkundea4

(d) Zergapetzea, ohiko ezkerrak ulertzen ez duena5

(ie) Historia pixka bat, baten batek bazekien, noiz eta 1946an6

(f) Politika fiskala, ohiko ezkerrak ulertzen ez duena7

(g) Galdera batzuk (ea ezkerrak ulertuko duen!)8

(h) Banku zentralak eta zorra (ea ezkerrak ulertuko duen!)9

Beraz,

So what sense might we make of the assertion that the Australian government has “less firepower” to respond to a new crisis? Answer: no sense at all.

(i) Etorkizunean, zer? (Ea ezkerrak ulertuko duen!)10

(j) Eta kazetariak, zer? (Ea ikasiko duten!) : “I wrote about this topic recently in this blog When journalists allow dangerous economic myths to pervade

(k) Fiskalitatea eta zor publikoa, berriz (ea guztiek ulertuko duten!)11

(l) Langabezia (ea guztiek ikasiko duten!)12

(m) Estatistikaz hitz bi13

(n) Politikarik eta kazetariak14

(o) Estatistika: metodologia15

Ondorioa:

Azkenean, nahasketa, Grezia (sic) aipatuz16, analisi faltsu eta tranpatia, eta onenean, propaganda kaxkarra17.


2 Ingelesez: “I (…) read an Opinion piece, which would serve as a classic demonstration for statistical students of how to confuse causation with correlation. It would also serve as a classic piece for macroeconomics students on how to completely misunderstand the role of fiscal policy and the dynamics that are associated with it. All round an excellent learning piece – in the right hands. But in the hands of the normal reader, not versed in these matters, the Opinion piece is a trashy piece of dangerous propaganda, which serves to indoctrinate the readership into believing that the correct policy path is, in fact, exactly the opposite of the responsible policy path for governments. It still amazes me how this sort of rubbish can parade as serious public offerings to the economic debate. It was an appallingly ignorant article. One of the worst you might read.”

3 Ingelesez: “The article (August 1, 2016) – The higher the government debt, the slower economic growth – was written by a conservative (Liberal) Federal Member of Parliament, David Coleman, who doesn’t have a background, it seems in economics and was a management consultant before entering politics.

He claims that “Government debt matters” and the argument he presents is simple (and simplistic):

4 Ingelesez: “1. “The greater the debt, the greater the proportion of government revenue that’s spent paying off interest bills”.

Yes, that is true by definition at constant interest rates (yields). But then the country with the highest gross public debt (Japan) is now paying negative interest rates for debt that extends out beyond 10 years, so in fact, ‘investors’ are paying the government to borrow.

But the point is, how does a rising proportion of government revenue matched by interest payments to the non-government sector impair real GDP growth?

The government debt holdings are part of the wealth portfolio of the non-government sector, held presumably because the assets are risk free (where the currency issuer is the national government) and provide a safe haven in times of uncertainty.

The interest payments represent income to the non-government sector, which helps underpin its subsequent spending.

More spending, in turn, supports higher real output levels, which is ‘growth’.

5 Ingelesez: “2. “The greater the interest bill, the less capacity to reduce tax”.

This is a true statement, but not for the reasons that the author would comprehend given his approach.

The truth lies in understanding the purpose of taxation in a fiat currency system. In an intrinsic sense, taxation revenue is never needed to raise funds for the government in order that it can spend.

Please read my blog – Taxpayers do not fund anything – for more discussion on this point.

A sovereign government is never revenue constrained because it is the monopoly issuer of the currency.

In a fiat currency system, the government might impose taxes to control inflation – taxation is a way that government imposes limits on the non-government sector’s capacity to spend and thus create real resource ‘space’ for government spending in pursuit of its social objectives without overreaching the capacity of the economy to respond by increasing real output.

One way of thinking about this is that taxation creates unemployment in the non-government sector and government spending creates the demand for goods and services which solves the unemployment.

The other reasons why a government might tax are:

(a) To redistribute purchasing power from the rich to the poor (high income to low income) – a point that is obvious.

(b) To alter the allocation of resources away from undesirable ends – such as tobacco or carbon taxes – making undesirable products more expensive in order to discourage use.

(c) To provide some hypothecated public transparency for major projects/programs like highways – politically contentious spending should be transparent. Taxes are, in fact, ‘demand drains’ and so reduce the capacity of the non-government sector to spend. In this sense, the transparency allows the non-government sector to see exactly what ‘demand injection’ (say highway spending) is replacing the command on resources that households and firms would have had in the absence of the taxes. It has nothing to do with the taxes funding anything. Just a $-for-$ matching to help expose the opportunity cost.”

6 Ingelesez: “In 1946, the American statistician and economistBeardsley Ruml – who wrote that “Taxes for Revenue are Obsolete” clearly understood all of this.

He understood that a primary role for taxation was “the maintenance of a dollar which has a stable purchasing power … the avoidance of inflation” and wrote that:

If federal taxes are insufficient or of the wrong kind, the purchasing power in the hands of the public is likely to be greater than the output of goods and services with which this purchasing demand can be satisfied.

The result would be inflation. Note that implicit in this statement is that the government wants to command a certain quantity of the available real goods and services to fulfill its socio-economic program.

The excessive private sector purchasing power is thus assessed relative to the total available real output and the government’s desire to command some of that output.

So if you think about the primary purpose of taxation in a fiat currency monetary system is to control purchasing power then it is logically true that if income payments being received by the non-government sector in the form of interest payments on government debt holdings rise and the economy is already operating at full capacity, then the capacity to reduce taxes is reduced.

Why? Because the higher income payments and low tax revenue at full employment would run the economy up against the inflation barrier and necessitate either higher taxes or less government spending.

But if there are idle productive resources, then the author’s statement is false. The government could increase total interest payments to the non-government sector and cut taxes to stimulate overall spending if it thought that the non-government sector should have a greater command of the increasing productive resources brought back into effective use.”

7 Ingelesez: “3. “And the greater the debt, the less firepower government has to deal with issues as they arise. That firepower matters a lot in a low interest rate environment, where the impact of monetary policy is muted.”

By “firepower”, the author is presumably meaning the fiscal capacity to intervene when total spending is weak and unemployment is rising.

The author is just jumping on the mindless neo-liberal bandwagon, which claims that the capacity of governments to respond in the next crisis is exhausted because the deficits rose in the last crisis.

The proposition that the government has run out of ammunition/firepower, etc is regularly rehearsed.

It is a totally false proposition.

The author is clearly discussing fiscal policy, given he recognises that monetary policy is largely ineffective (although for him, it is because of low interest rates, which is another false proposition that I will leave for today).

8 Ingelesez: “How would he respond to the following points:

1. Doesn’t the Australian government issue its own currency? Doesn’t that mean it can purchase anything that is available for sale in that currency (AUDs) and that means all idle labour if it so wished?

2. How can a government that issues its own currency not have “much left in their lockers”? Such a government can never run out of money. Read: NEVER.

3. Even if the private financial markets were to turn against government debt (and they won’t!), the Australian government can still spend without issuing it.

It is just a voluntary (ideological) convention that says that a fiat currency-issuing government has to match its fiscal deficit with an equal $-value of debt issuance. There is nothing intrinsic in that convention.

4. Even if the Australian government chose to continue issuing debt to allow the private markets to have a risk free asset to price risk off (that is, maintained the current system of corporate welfare), could not the RBA purchase all that debt and control yields should the non-government sector boycott the issue? Clearly it could.

9 Ingelesez: “Under the old ‘tap’ system, where the government set the yield it would pay investors and then called for private bids, the central bank had to stand ready to buy whatever volume the private investors were unwilling to take up, including all of the issue.

This raised issues of ‘central bank funding’ and once the Monetarist/neo-liberals took over they altered the system to the ‘auction’ model where the private sector determines the yield on the basis of demand and the central bank stays out of the auction.

But all of that is just smoke and mirrors. The central bank could at any time buy all the (unnecessary) public debt. If you examine the rising proportion of public debt held by the US Federal Reserve, the Bank of Japan and the ECB you will see that is so.

The bottom line is that a sovereign government like Australia can never run out of money and never needs to issue public debt as a matter of necessity. The public debt issuance is entirely voluntary and such voluntary actions have a habit of being quickly changed if they present too many ‘political’ problems.

It is thus a total lie to claim that a government will inevitably run out of domestic funding sources. All the discussions about AAA ratings are also irrelevant (and for Britain today given the corrupt ratings agencies have tried to steal some limelight and downgraded the rating).

Please read my blogs – Ratings agencies and higher interest rates and Time to outlaw the credit rating agencies – for more discussion on why the ratings agencies should be ignored in the context of public debt.

Ratings agencies cannot push up yields on government debt issuance unless the government lets them.

10 Ingelesez: “Whether the government has been running surpluses or deficits in the past is largely irrelevant to what it can do in the future?

Its outstanding liabilities (public debt) do not place any constraint on its capacity to spend. As we are seeing around the world, central banks can ensure interest rates stay low if they want which has the effect of dramatically reducing any interest payments on the public debt.

The Australian government can always spend what it wants irrespective of whether it has been running surpluses or deficits in the past.

The deficits it created during the GFC after several years of surplus (with the result that private debt skyrocketed) do not constrain what it can do tomorrow.

So the claim that Australia has no further ammunition in a fiscal sense is a lie.

11 Ingelesez: “Which brings me to the next point the author makes which statistics students would see through straight away but which apparently evades the grasp (intentionally or not) of the author.

He says:

Our government inherited a large debt from its forebear, which managed to turn cash in the bank in 2007 into a big credit card bill by 2013. Reducing that debt is not the only economic task of government – but it is a major one.

The author fails to mention that in between 2007 and 2013, there was the worst global economic crash since the Great Depression and had the Australian government not introduced the rather large (but not large enough) and early fiscal stimulus in late 2008 and early 2009 (in three stages), our economy would have gone the way of the world – into deep recession.

The author fails to mention that Australia (as a result of that timely fiscal stimulus) was the only advanced nation to avoid an official recession.

The author fails to mention that had the government not introduced that fiscal stimulus, the resulting deep recession would have pushed up the fiscal deficit anyway (via the automatic stabilisers) and, as a result of the neo-liberal convention that the deficits have to be matched by public debt issuance (to pretend that the debt is funding the government spending), the debt would have also risen anyway.

Look around the world! The result would have been much higher unemployment and underemployment and greater income losses than actually occurred.

The author’s failure to contextualise the shift into higher public debt is a dishonesty. Whether it is a deliberate act or one of stupidity, I cannot tell.

Please read my blogMMT Fiscal Principles – for more discussion on this point.

Further, a major goal of the federal (or any currency-issuing) government is not to reduce public debt. The major goal is to provide sufficient net deficit spending to allow the non-government sector to achieve its saving desires and ensure total spending is sufficient to fully utilise the available productive capacity.”

12 Ingelesez: “At present, Australia’s labour underutilisation rate (according to the ABS) is around 14.2 per cent – with 734,200 unemployed and 1,067.3 thousand persons underemployed – making a total of 1,801.5 thousand workers either unemployed or underemployed.

Further, the current participation rate is well down on its recent (November 2010) peak, which means that hidden unemployment has risen since then by some 180 thousand workers as a result of the poor employment growth.

Please read my blog – Australian labour market – stagnating due to lack of overall spending – for more discussion on this point.

So in terms of the major responsibility of a national government, the current policy settings signify massive failure – and the way to redress that failure is for the Australian government to engage in a rather substantial increase in its fiscal deficit (by more than 2 per cent of GDP).

Given the institutional structure where debt is issued to match the deficit, the result of the Australian government conducting itself responsibly would be higher – not lower – public debt levels.

13 Ingelesez: “The author then engages in a bit of statistics – although it is about as sophisticated as the fraudulent (or incompetent) spreadsheet display that Rogoff and Reinhart presented in 2010 to try to convince people that an 80 per cent public debt to GDP ratio was a dangerous threshold for nations to pass.

(…)

The author I am discussing today, similarly, fired up a spreadsheet, and apparently ‘found’:

a striking relationship between levels of government debt and economic growth. Generally, the higher government debt, the less economic growth.

Well, isn’t that surprising!

He used OECD data “for 29 member nations” (conflating currency-issuing governments with those who use a foreign currency as in Eurozone Member States – huge error number 1) and:

Of the 29 nations, I grouped them into the 10 with the lowest levels of debt in 2014, the middle 10, and the nine with the highest levels of debt. I then compared their levels of debt with their levels of economic growth.

The results were striking. Between 2009-2014, the nations with the lowest levels of debt grew on average by 28 per cent in US dollar terms. The middle 10 nations grew by 21 per cent in the same period. And the nine nations with the largest levels of debt grew by just 12 per cent in the period from 2009 to 2014. The three nations with the lowest levels of economic growth – Greece, Portugal, and Spain – all had very high levels of government debt when compared to other nations.

Question for students in Economic Statistics 101: Critically evaluate the veracity of the statement and the methodology used?

Answer: the methodology does not substantiate any causality betweeen public debt levels and rates of economic growth.

Therefore the conclusion the author draws is unable to be supported from this exercise.”

14 Ingelesez: As in the case of Rogoff and Reinhart who also ‘eye-ball’ two columns of data, the only thing that is established is some sort of correlation between the two columns. The causality issue is not explored at all – but merely asserted.

All the financial journalists and politicians – right up to the top – did not tell the world that Rogoff and Reinhart were only providing correlations. They treated the results as if they were causal – from public debt ratios to growth.

And in the case of Rogoff and Reinhart, when the ‘mistake’ was corrected – that is key data was added back into the ‘correlation’ analysis, the relationship they had found disappeared anyway.

In the current case, all that this author has discovered is that under current institutional arrangements where public debt is issued to match fiscal deficits, when economic growth falters, public debt rises.

Why is that? It is obvious. When growth slows down, tax revenue falls and welfare payments rise – automatically (this is the cyclical component of the fiscal balance). The government policy does not have to change for that to happen.

So when growth slows, fiscal deficits rise even if government policy is unchanged, and as a result of these unnecessary institutional arrangements (for currency-issuing governments that is), the public debt levels rise.

Once we understand these relationships it is highly likely the causality runs the opposite way to that being asserted by this author.

Countries with rising public debt or rising public debt to GDP ratios are those which are facing recession or economic slowdown. In the case of the public debt ratio, the denominator (GDP) falls while the numerator (outstanding debt) rises, given the cyclical response of the fiscak balance (independent of any discretionary fiscal stimulus that such a nation might enjoy).

In other words, the causality flows from growth to debt not the other way round.

There is a large literature on this issue. For example, this point was made in this article from April 22, 2012 – Is high public debt harmful for economic growth?.”

15 Ingelesez: “The authors employ a nice statistical technique to try to sort out the causality issue between economic growth and public debt.

Their results allow them to:

reject the notion that debt causes slower growth in OECD countries. We do confirm the oft-noted negative correlation between debt and growth, but show that debt does not have a causal effect on growth …Indeed, none of the papers in the literature on debt-growth links can make a strong claim the debt has a causal effect on economic growth …There are many papers that show that public debt is negatively correlated with economic growth.There is no paper that makes a convincing case for a causal link going from debt to growth.

Okay, that is my reading of the literature as well.

So, if this author was in a Economic Statistics 101 class he would fail badly such is the poverty of his scholarship.”

16 Ingelesez: “But then he wasn’t really engaging in scholarship anyway – more crude propaganda.

He finished the Op Ed piece by ramping up the hysteria about debt default and the problems Greece is currently enduring.

Dishonest analysis all of it.

17 Ingelesez: “… a dishonest propaganda rag – at best.

Utzi erantzuna

Zure e-posta helbidea ez da argitaratuko. Beharrezko eremuak * markatuta daude