The Modern Monetary Theory Perspective on the external economy
(https://billmitchell.org/blog/wp-content/uploads/2024/07/Trade_William_Mitchell_June_3_2022.pdf)
William Mitchell
June 2022
1. Introduction
There are three types of constraints that impact on decision making in an economic setting: (a)
financial; (b) real resource; and (c) political. These constraints can work independently or
together to alter the feasible decision-making environment. The problem is that many
economists conflate these constraints and produce erroneous analyses as a result. This is
particularly the case when it comes to analysing the capacities and opportunities of currency-
issuing governments and contextualising this analysis within an open economy setting with
trade and capital flows. Modern Monetary Theory (MMT) provides a clear framework for
distinguishing between these types of constraints because it accurately constructs the way
governments spend and successfully disentangles these constraints in an analytical way in an
open economy setting.
In this paper, we consider the way in which MMT constructs the external sector. We argue, in
part, that criticisms mounted against this view reflect the fact that much of the mainstream
macroeconomics and open economy analysis is predicated on understandings that were
relevant during the fixed exchange rate era. In particular, the way fiscal policy constraints are
perceived within the mainstream theory are directly related to the ‘constraints’ faced by fiscal
authorities during that period who had to ensure they did not compromise the central bank’s
primary responsibility to maintain external currency stability. Once exchange rate flexibility
freed macroeconomic policy (monetary and fiscal) to pursue domestic policy goals, those
‘constraints’ became inapplicable.
However, many economists, still consider currency vulnerability in the face of global financial
trends remains the greatest challenge facing any government, which embarks on an
expansionary policy program. The fear of currency collapse is shared by mainstream and many
heterodox economists, which in the view of this author has hampered the progress of non-
mainstream macroeconomic analysis. While the mainstream economists propose a raft of
fictions about both the domestic and external economies to mount their case against MMT,
many heterodox economists focus on what they consider to be a balance-of-payments-
constraint on fiscal policy. We analyse the ‘balance-of-payments-constrained-growth’ (BPCG)
theory and conclude that, if there is a binding constraint, it comes from politics rather than
finance or the real economy.
2. A real resource starting point
On August 15, 1971, US President Nixon suspended convertibility of the US dollar, which
effectively ended the fixed exchange rates system (Bretton Woods), which had organised
international currencies since 1946. After a futile attempt to salvage the broken system
(Smithsonian Agreement), the Jamaica Accords in 1976 formally ended the arrangement and
the era of fiat monetary systems began.
Under Bretton Woods, central banks had to manage the supply of their currencies to ensure the
agreed parities were maintained. An excess supply of a currency in foreign exchange markets
required the responsible central bank to purchase that currency using their foreign currency
reserves and/or to increase domestic interest rates to attract foreign investment to redress the
downward pressure.
But the money supply contraction and higher interest rates pushed unemployment up and if
expansionary fiscal policy was used too aggressively to reduce unemployment – putting
currency back in the system – it would compromise the central bank’s efforts to maintain
currency stability. Consequently, without an increase in gold reserves, increased government
expenditure (injecting currency) had to be matched (‘financed’) by taxation and if they wanted
to spend more than their tax revenue, they had to issue debt (draining currency).
The collapse of Bretton Woods dramatically altered the opportunities available to currency-
issuing governments. First, under a fiat monetary system, ‘state money’ no longer had any
intrinsic value. For an otherwise ‘worthless’ currency to be acceptable in exchange some
motivation was required. That motivation emerged because the sovereign government required
its use to relinquish private tax obligations.
Second, as the central bank no longer had to defend the floating currency, it followed that there
was no financial constraint on government spending. Currency-issuing governments can buy
any goods and services that are available for sale in its currency including all idle labour. The
only meaningful constraint is the ‘inflationary ceiling’ that is reached when all productive
resources are full employed. This is a dramatic change. Accordingly, we traverse from thinking
about financial constraints on government spending and all the negative narratives about the
need to ‘fund’ spending, to a focus on real resource constraints defined in terms of available
productive resources and available final goods and services.
Third, logically, the government no longer needs to issue debt and debt issuance serves other
purposes which evade public scrutiny (Mitchell et al., 2019).
Thus, it was a major shift in the organisation of the external economy, which spawned the
evolution of the modern fiat monetary systems and provided the point of departure for MMT.
Accordingly, MMT economists shift the focus from financial aggregates (such as deficit-to-
GDP ratios) to the functional outcomes that are desired from public spending given the
available real resources. In that regard,
The shift in focus carries over to the way that the external economy is introduced into the
macroeconomic framework (Mitchell et al., 2019; Mitchell, 2023). The interaction between
nations is driven, in part, by a desire to expand their respective consumption possibilities.
Nations produce to consume. From a material or real resource perspective, a particular nation
benefits from receiving goods and services rather than sending them elsewhere.
Exporting goods and services incurs an opportunity cost in the form of real resources that could
be used locally being made available to other nations (as raw materials or final products).
Imports occur when other nations transfer their real resources to the importing nation, depriving
their own citizens of their use. MMT thus starts with the observation that exports represent a
cost and imports a benefit. In this vein, trade deficits allow a nation to enjoy a higher material
living standard. Trade surpluses are achieved by depriving local citizens of a higher material
standard of living – in the sense that they are being underpaid, under consuming, and/or
working too hard.
Nations thus incur the export ‘cost’ to generate benefits that are otherwise unattainable, given
their domestic resource base, to enhance the material prosperity of the nation. MMT considers
the export cost to be an investment in generating an increased capacity to import to expand
consumption possibilities. A trade deficit is a sign that the real terms of trade are working in
favour of the deficit nation.
The focus on real resources also has significant implications for how we conceive of fiscal
space. The purpose of fiscal policy is not to achieve some financial target, but rather to achieve
functional outcomes, such as full employment. Accordingly, MMT considers the desired fiscal
position would be whatever is required, given the spending, and saving decisions of the non-
government sector, to maintain full capacity output.
Fiscal space is thus a real, not a financial concept. Fiscal space is exhausted when there are no
idle resources available for sale. The question then arises as to whether the external economy
impacts on the fiscal space. More specifically is there a balance-of-payments constraint on
government net spending? We will consider that question in Sections 4 and 5.
3. Understanding the financial transactions and trade
The basic macroeconomic rule is that spending equals income equals output, which drives
employment. The starting point in macroeconomics, then, is to consider the determinants of
the expenditure sources. Later, the analysis is complicated to include a focus on the supply-
side, which leads to the distinction between quantity-adjustment and price-adjustment and
introduces the possibility that spending becomes constrained by productive capacity (Okun,
1981).
International trade is a significant determinant of national income movements in most nations,
given that total expenditure in any period is the sum of domestic demand (household
consumption, business investment and government spending) and net exports. Net exports is
the difference between an injection (exports) and a leakage (imports) from the income-
expenditure stream. Expenditure on imported goods and services means that some of the
national income produced in a period does not return to local firms, which reduces output and
income, other things equal. Exports are generated by external factors and boost local
production and income and can help offset the imports leakage.
Import spending rises with national income and is also influenced by exchange rate movements
and relative inflation rates between nations Exports are similarly influenced by the real
exchange rate as well as economic conditions in the foreign country. So as a nation’s economic
growth increases, it will import more goods and services. As world growth increases, exports
from a nation will typically rise (Robinson, 1947, Part III; Mitchell et al., 2019).
While the impact of trade on the national accounts is broadly uncontroversial, there are many
misconceptions surrounding the financial aspects of the transactions between a nation and the
rest of the world that are recorded in the Balance of Payments. These misconceptions often
motivate erroneous claims about the solvency of national governments, which, in turn, restricts
responsible policy choices from being taken. MMT provides a clear framework for
understanding the implications of these transactions
A trade deficit means that foreigners have given up more real resources (inputs, final goods)
than they have received in return. Why would they do that? The answer is that a trade deficit
allows foreigners to accumulate financial assets in the currencies of deficit nations. If the
foreigners change their desires to hold financial or other assets denominated in the currency of
the deficit nation, then the trade flows will change as the deficit nation’s real terms of trade
worsen because it becomes harder to get the foreign exchange necessary to maintain the same
level of imports.
It is possible that foreigners will have no desire to accumulate financial assets in a particular
foreign currency, which means that nation would have to run trade balances. It is also possible
that the preference for foreign currency financial assets could change quickly, which could be
highly disruptive for the deficit nation. In general, however, these adjustments are not sudden.
We can also extend the MMT insight, that net financial assets can only be created and destroyed
in the non-government sector through transactions with the government (central bank and/or
treasury), to an analysis of trade.
Consider the following story:
§ I wish to buy a Japanese manufactured car, where the manufacturer measures profit and
loss in yen.
§ The manufacturer maintains a dealer network in, say, Australia and invoices dealers in yen.
§ The car dealership accepts the yen-liability but sells the car in Australian dollars ($A).
§ When I pay the dealer, my bank reduces my deposit balance by the price of the car and the
balance at dealer’s bank is increased by the same amount.
§ The Australian central bank records a decrease in reserves for my bank and a corresponding
increase in reserves for the car dealer’s bank as part of the clearing process, which just
means that the ownership of these $A transfers to the dealer. No new net financial assets
are created.
§ Alternatively, if I take out a loan to buy the car, then my bank’s balance sheet now records
the loan as an asset and creates a deposit (the loan) on the liability side. When I hand over
the cheque to the car dealer (drawing on the loan), the dealer now has a new asset (bank
deposit) via the fact that loans create deposits within the system. Again, no new net
financial assets are created.
At this stage, the export surplus (1 car) manifests as an accumulation of $A assets in the form
of a bank deposit (or equivalent). What happens next depends on the aspirations of the
manufacturer. There are several options:
1. Require the invoice to the dealer to be paid in yen.
2. Leave the sales revenue in $A accounts at Australian banks.
3. Purchase $A-denominated assets (financial or otherwise).
A currency mismatch would arise if the car dealer decides to pay the invoice from the
manufacturer in yen. Accordingly, after deducting profits, the car dealer will then negotiate an
$A for yen sale in the foreign exchange market (probably via their bank). That sale can only
proceed if a current yen holder desires to hold $A. Once the contract exchange takes place, the
car dealer transfers the yen purchased from the counterparty to the Japanese bank of the car
manufacturer (ignoring almost certain hedging arrangements).
The resulting financial effects are: (a) The $A balances in the Australian financial sector remain
the same, only the ownership of the balances changes; (b) The yen balances in the Japanese
financial sector remain the same but ownership has transferred from the Foreign Exchange
dealer to the car dealer and finally to the car manufacturer. If the manufacturer decided to
accept payment of the invoice in $A (then the foreign exchange market transaction would be
unnecessary) and the transaction would just mean that the Japanese car company would have
a new $A financial asset (bank deposit). In summary, the net export surplus does not increase
the yen or $A balances – only the ownership of these currency holdings changes.
What would happen if the Japanese car firm accepted payment in $A assets and bought
Australian Government debt with the $A-denominated bank deposits? In this case, the
Japanese car company would instruct its agent to put in an order for the bonds and the firm
would instruct its Australian bank to transfer the $A bank deposit to the favour of the bond
seller (which might be the central bank). The Japanese car maker’s lawyers or representative,
in turn, would receive the bond certificate and the Australian government’s foreign debt rises
by that amount. In this case, the Australian Government promises, on maturity of the bond, to
credit the bank account of the ultimate holder of the bond with the face value of the bond plus
interest and debit some account at the central bank (or whatever specific accounting structure
is involved with bond sales and purchases).
In other words, this transaction merely amounts to substituting a non-interest bearing reserve
balance for an interest-bearing Government bond. That transaction can never present any
problems of solvency for a sovereign government despite many commentators (and
economists) arguing that without the foreign funding, the government would have no financial
viability. The corollary to this narrative is that the foreigners could suddenly change their
preferences and the government would become insolvent.
Let’s clear that misconception up using Chinese trade surpluses against the US as an example
and drawing on the understanding we have achieved to date. China automatically accumulates
US-dollar denominated claims because of these surpluses. They are the ‘reward’ for running
the real terms of trade in favour of the US. These claims are initially held within the US banking
system and can manifest as US-dollar deposits or interest-bearing bonds. The difference is
immaterial to how the US government spends.
Of course, the US car worker in Detroit who endures unemployment because of the cheaper
imports coming from China, is unlikely to consider the superior real terms of trade the US
enjoys an advantage. But the US, overall, benefits from China’s willingness to deprive its
citizens of the use of its own real resources so that it can net ship its ‘labour’ and other real
resources embodied in the exports to other nations.
What would happen if the Chinese holders of US government debt decided to liquidate their
holdings of US government debt that have been accumulated using the $US-denominated trade
surpluses? This could be done slowly or quickly. A rapid liquidation (conversion into Chinese
currency) would devastate the Chinese wealth stored in those $US assets because the $US
would depreciate significantly. Such a liquidation would have no bearing on the US
government’s capacity to buy goods and services for sale in US dollars but would seriously
undermine the international competitiveness of China.
4. The external sector and sustainable policy space
The late Canadian economist Harry Johnson (1969: 18) noted that:
The adoption of flexible exchange rates would have the great advantage of freeing
governments to use their instruments of domestic policy for the pursuit of domestic
objectives, while at the same time removing the pressures to intervene in international
trade and payments for balance-of-payments reasons.
A flexible exchange rate regime maximises the policy space for government to pursue domestic
objectives. Once a nation adopts a currency peg of any description (fixed exchange rate,
dollarisation, currency board, etc) it loses its full currency sovereignty and compromises
domestic policy aspirations.
In this section, we develop a concept of sustainable policy space. The well-known sectoral
balances framework, which is derived from the national accounting framework can be depicted
graphically (see Mitchell et al., 2019).
The sectoral balances accounting statement is written:
(1) (S – I) = (G – T) + CAB
where S is household saving, I is private capital formation, G is government spending, T is
taxation revenue and CAB is the Current Account balance (which is the sum of exports (X)
minus imports (M) plus net external income flows (FNI)).
Equation (1) is interpreted as meaning that government sector deficits (G – T > 0) and current
account surpluses (CAB > 0) generate national income and net financial assets for the private
domestic sector, which must then be saving overall (S > I). Saving overall is different to the
residual flow of saving that is left after household consumption decisions are executed.
Conversely, government surpluses (G – T < 0) and current account deficits (CAB < 0) reduce
national income and undermine the capacity of the private domestic sector to add financial
assets.
Figure 1 Sustainable policy space
Source: Mitchell et al. (2019).
In Figure 1, all points above zero on the vertical axis represent a government fiscal surplus and
all points on the vertical axis below the origin denote government fiscal deficits. Similarly, all
points to the right of the origin on the horizontal axis denote external surpluses and all points
to the left of the origin on the horizontal axis represent external deficits. These balances are
usually expressed as shares of GDP. Clearly, the origin of both axes denotes a position where
all balances are equal to zero.
We also know that when the private domestic balance is zero (S = I), then the government fiscal
deficit (surplus) will equal the external deficit (surplus). Thus, the diagonal 45-degree line (AC)
shows all combinations of government fiscal balances and external balances where the private
domestic balance is zero.
At points a and c, there is a private domestic balance. Point b corresponds to a fiscal deficit and
an external surplus. Thus, the private sector must be engaging in positive net saving. Then
between points b and a, and b and c, net saving by the private sector is falling until private
domestic balance is achieved at points a and c, respectively.
Similarly, at d, the private domestic sector is net spending. Between points d and c and d and
a, net spending by the private sector declines until private domestic balance is achieved at
points a and c respectively.
We can generalise this knowledge and conclude that all points above the 45-degree line on
each side of the vertical axis correspond to private domestic sector deficits and all points below
the 45-degree line on each side of the vertical axis correspond to private domestic sector
surpluses.
Several observations are then possible. First, for a sovereign, currency-issuing government, all
combinations of the sectoral balances represented by the points in the four quadrants are
permissible. With private sector spending and saving decisions combining with the flows of
income arising from trade with the external sector driving national income, the government
sector can allow its balance to adjust to whatever magnitude is required to maintain full
employment and price stability.
For example, when a trade deficit coincides with overall private domestic sector saving, the
drain on aggregate demand requires the government to run a deficit of sufficient size to ensure
that total spending is sufficient to absorb the real productive capacity available in the economy.
Alternatively, if there is a trade surplus, which adds to total demand and the private domestic
sector is in deficit, then the government has to ensure it ran a surplus of sufficient size to ensure
that the economy does not overheat and exhaust its productive capacity. The strong economy
would be associated with robust tax revenue growth, which would help the government achieve
its surplus. Discretionary adjustments in spending and taxation rates might also be required.
Second, while these combinations are permissible, the private domestic sector cannot easily
sustain deficits permanently because they manifest in an increasing stock of debt. There is a
difference, however, between private domestic deficits driven by consumption expenditure and
those driven by capital expenditure. In the latter case, a capital importing nation, for example,
may well record private domestic and external trade deficits as firms invest in productive
capital, which delivers a profitable rate of return, that, in turn, allows the increasing
indebtedness to be serviced. In that case, the private domestic sector may be able to sustain
deficits while economic growth is uninterrupted.
The process of private debt accumulation is limited because at some point the susceptibility of
the private balance sheet to cyclical movements (for example, rising unemployment, falling
sales) increases and the risk of default rises. The only unambiguously sustainable position is
for the private domestic sector to be in surplus. An economy can absorb deviations from that
position but only for short periods. Thus, it is only the area ABC that can be considered the
sustainable policy space available to governments that issue their own currency.
Third, any imposition of fiscal rules (for example, the 3 per cent threshold in the EMU Stability
and Growth Pact), will shrink the sustainable fiscal space significantly. An unconstrained
government can always utilise the available space to ensure aggregate demand is sufficient to
maintain full employment and price stability. While the external surplus nations have more
policy flexibility when operating under a fiscal rule than external deficit nations, the fact
remains that the allowable fiscal deficits may be insufficient to maintain the aggregate demand
necessary to sustain full employment.
The policy inflexibility facing nations which run external deficits and simultaneously must
operate under fiscal rules becomes even more restrictive. When such an economy experiences
a negative economic shock significant enough to drive the private domestic sector to reduce its
spending and target a sectoral surplus, the extent to which the fiscal deficit can be used to
absorb the loss of overall aggregate demand is very limited. It is highly likely that such an
economy will experience enduring recessions because of the artificial fiscal rules (restrictions)
that are placed on its government.
However, the contention that policies that situate the economy in the area ABC are sustainable
is contested by those who assert that nations must ultimately sustain growth rates consistent
with trade balance. This view is broadly referred to as ‘balance-of-payments-growth-
constraint’ (BPGC) theory, which we turn to now.
5. The Balance-of-Payments Constraint debate
Critics essentially assert that MMT is flawed because it doesn’t recognise the fiscal limits
imposed by the need to maintain a stable trade balance. Much of this argument is based on
fixed exchange rate logic, despite being applied to nations adopting flexible exchange rates. A
hangover from the fixed exchange rate period is the view that trade deficits are unsustainable.
Belkar et al. (2007: 1) state:
Perhaps the key concern is that countries in this situation could be on a path to
insolvency, building up excessive net foreign debt, raising the prospects of default
and/or a sharp reversal in capital flows, which might force an abrupt and costly
adjustment … Also, large deficits and rising indebtedness could leave countries more
vulnerable to adverse external shocks (including a change in sentiment of foreign
creditors).
Clearly under fixed exchange rates, persistent current account deficits are problematic and
compromise the ability of nations to pursue domestic policy targets. During the Bretton Woods
period, nations endured recurring ‘stop-go’ growth cycles, where fiscal authorities would be
forced to tighten fiscal policy and create unemployment to support their central bank’s efforts
to stabilise the currency in the face of external deficits. Then, to address falling political
popularity, they would stimulate the economy, which would increase import expenditure and
precipitate a new round of currency pressures (Hood and Himaz, 2017).
Some economists point to the UK experience in the 1992 as evidence of the damage that
speculative capital can wreak on a nation through the external sector, and, as a result, most
economists urge governments to reduce their current account deficits and target surpluses.
Unfortunately, these critiques fail to trace the source of the 1992-93 currency crisis, which
demonstrated that fixing exchange rates between economies that are disparate in structure and
performance will always fail with mobile capital (see Mitchell, 2015, for a detailed analysis).
The problem is that, even though most of the world has moved to flexible exchange rates, Black
Wednesday, and similar crises under fixed exchange rates, have become the model for those
who predict that the amorphous financial speculators will destroy a currency if governments
run fiscal deficits and/or current account deficits. Even heterodox economists (Post
Keynesians, Marxists) mount fears of insolvency and currency instability arising from external
deficits (see for example, McCombie and Roberts, 2002; Epstein, 2020).
While mainstream economics is predicated on a confusion between financial and real resource
constraints, Post Keynesians and Marxists often conflate political constraints with financial
constraints, especially when considering the balance of payments. They use the BPCG
framework to claim that attempts by the government to stimulate growth will fail if they result
in current account deficits. In terms of Figure 1, they argue the sustainable area is much smaller
than we demonstrated in Section 4. We argue here that the balance-of-payments-constraint can
only be understood in political terms and says nothing about financial and/or real resource
constraints. In that regard, the BPCG approach does not provide a basis for discrediting MMT.
The BPCG approach grew out of the work of Hicks (1950), Kaldor (1957, 1970, 1971, 1978,
1989) and Thirlwall (1979). While mainstream growth theory posits that the constraints on
progress are to be found on the supply-side (technology, population, etc) with the demand-side
(expenditure) always adjusting to ensure there is no idle capacity along the growth path, Post
Keynesian approaches, following Marx, Kalecki and Keynes seek to shift the focus to the
demand-side constraints. However, the BPCG approach places a particular meaning on the
demand-side constraints. It is not domestic demand failures that ultimately matter but export
demand. Mitchell (2023) considers this literature in some detail.
Kaldor (1957: 593) argued that ‘the general level of output at any one time is limited by
available resources, and not by effective demand’ and thus characterised the shortage of labour
as the binding constraint. Clearly, at full capacity no further real output will be forthcoming
which is a central MMT proposition. However, in his later work, Kaldor (1970, 1978)
abandoned that view, and, instead, claimed that it was export demand that limited a nation’s
growth potential. He assumed that export revenue was the only source of expenditure injection,
which, in turn, induced increases in domestic expenditure. Accordingly, after an export boost,
domestic expenditure would rise on the income stimulus and once the new leakages equalled
the initial external exogenous boost, the growth constraint would reassert itself because the
nation would run out of reserves to purchase its imports. In other words, growth was only
possible through the accumulation of foreign exchange reserves via export demand.
Kaldor (1970: 146) summarised his long-run relationship between aggregate output and export
spending using the Harrodian foreign trade multiplier, which he reinterpreted as the growth
constraint:
- 𝑌 = 1/m 𝑋
where Y is aggregate output, X is total exogenous exports, and m is the marginal propensity to
import.
Thus, in the absence of any other exogenous spending sources, output growth will ultimately
be limited to the rate that is consistent with a trade balance. Importantly, there must also be
some adjustment process that ensures that balance, which in Kaldor’s approach is exclusively
determined by induced income changes rather than price changes.
From an MMT perspective, Kaldor’s treatment of government spending, which we typically
consider to have an autonomous or discretionary component, is problematic. Kaldor (1970)
assumed that government spending was financially constrained by endogenous changes in tax
revenue and always adjusts to those changes, thus denying the ability of government to run
persistent deficits or surpluses. Kaldor (1971: 7) also claimed that using fiscal policy to
increase ‘production and employment through a stimulus to domestic demand would …
increase imports relative to exports; this would have brought a downward pressure on sterling’.
It is surprising that heterodox economists ever accepted this neoclassical argument against
discretionary fiscal interventions.
Another interesting deviation by Kaldor from previous Keynesian growth theory was his
rejection of Harrod’s investment duality (Harrod, 1939), where capital formation: (a) added to
immediate aggregate spending; and (b) augmented future capacity, which then required growth
in future spending to absorb that productive potential and avoid recession. Kaldor considered
it was exports that were dual in nature because they not only added to total spending but also
created extra space (through foreign exchange earnings) for import spending to increase.
This duality is at the basis of the BPCG theory, formalised by Thirlwall (1979), which asserts
that the long-run growth process is constrained by a nation’s exports, assuming the real
exchange rate is constant and that balance of trade is zero (see also McCombie and Thirlwall,
1994).
Thirlwall (1979: 429) was investigating ‘why growth rates differ between countries’ and
criticised the neoclassical approach for ignored the fact that ‘it is demand that ‘drives’ the
economic system to which supply, within limits, adapts’ (p.429). This, in turn, focused his
attention on the ‘constraints on demand’ (p.429).
For Thirlwall (1979: 430):
The importance of a healthy balance of payments for growth can be stated quite
succinctly. If a country gets into balance of payments difficulties as it expands demand,
before the short term capacity growth rate is reached, then demand must be curtailed;
supply is never fully utilised; investment is discouraged; technological progress is
slowed down; and a country’s goods compared to foreign goods become less desirable
so worsening the balance of payments still further, and so on. A vicious circle is started.
By contrast, if a country is able to expand demand up to the level of existing productive
capacity, without balance of payments difficulties arising, the pressure of demand upon
capacity may well raise the capacity growth rate.
Note his reference to the ‘balance of payments’ is somewhat of a misnomer because he is really
talking about the trade balance.
Following Kaldor, Thirlwall starts with a strict condition on the growth rates of exports and
imports
- 𝑃dt Xt = Pft 𝑀t 𝐸t
where X is the volume of exports, Pd is the home currency price of exports, M is the volume of
imports, Pf is the foreign currency price of imports, E is the nominal exchange rate, and t is
time.
In growth terms, balance of payments equilibrium requires that growth in export revenue
continuously equals the growth in import expenditure
(4) 𝑝dt + 𝑥t = 𝑝ft +𝑚t + 𝑒t
where the lower-case letters depict growth rates.
Thirlwall adopted the standard assumptions about the determinants of exports and imports and
assumed that the ‘Marshall-Lerner condition is just satisfied or … relative prices measured in
a common currency do not change over the long run’ (Thirlwall, 1979; 434).
Then, imposing a balance of payments equilibrium condition (which is really a trade
equilibrium), we get
(5) 𝑦Bt = 1/π xt
where yBt is the balance of payments equilibrium growth rate and π is the income elasticity of
demand for imports and is assumed to be greater than 0.
Thirlwall (1979: 437) used this simple expression to assert that if a nation wishes ‘to grow
faster they must first raise the balance of payments constraint on demand’ and that must come
from increasing exports and/or reducing the income elasticity of imports.
What mechanisms did Thirlwall envisage that makes (5) binding on growth? McCombie (2011)
says that:
The rationale behind the law is that no country can grow faster than its balance-of-
payments equilibrium rate for very long, as its level of overseas debt to GDP ratio will
grow to levels that will precipitate a collapse in international confidence, the
downgrading of its international credit rating, and a sovereign debt and currency crisis.
Setterfield (2011: 397) expresses this in a different way:
a fundamental premise of BPCG theory in its original form is that we must observe
trade balance, either: a) because countries are unable to run chronic trade deficits (than
cannot attract permanent net inflows of financial capital from abroad); or b) because
countries are unwilling to run chronic trade deficits (they do not wish to attract
permanent net inflows of financial capital from abroad, because of the resulting
accumulation of foreign indebtedness and consequent debt servicing commitments)
(emphasis in original)
In one conception, it is the alleged power of global financial markets that impose the constraint,
and, in the other, it is the choice of governments, presumably based on a fear of the former.
Importantly, the first premise is only relevant to a fixed-exchange rate regime, while the second
premise is best understood as a political constraint.
Johnson (1969: 19), long ago, countered the argument that flexible exchange rates would be ‘unstable … jumping about from day to day’:
… in response to such changes in demand and supply — including changes induced by
changes in governmental policies — and normally will move only slowly and fairly
predictably. Abnormally rapid and erratic movements will occur only in response to
sharp and unexpected changes in circumstances; and such changes in a fixed exchange
rate system would produce equally or more uncertainty- creating policy changes in the
form of devaluation, deflation, or the imposition of new controls on trade and payments
While the fixed exchange rate system was ultimately derailed by speculative capital flows,
which threatened exhaustion of the foreign exchange and gold reserves of nations recording
trade deficits, no such constraints impact on nations running flexible exchange rates.
Further, the long-run constraint is not binding if the capital account offsets the current account
deficit. The introduction of financial flows on the capital account negates the Thirlwall
assumption that exports are required to pay for imported goods and services. In other words, a
nation could record permanent trade deficits, without degrading its currency.
Belkar et al. (2007: 4), representing the ‘modern’ central banking perspective under flexible
exchange rates, argue that:
The current account balance need not … be seen by itself as a reliable indicator of
vulnerabilities … The fact that Australia has managed to sustain investors’ confidence
is evident in the maintenance of the current account deficit at an average of around 41⁄2
per cent of GDP over two decades combined with a real exchange rate showing no
discernible trend over the same period.
So, in the case of financial flows, the maximum BPCG output level would be below the
possible output level. The question then is at what point do the net financial inflows stop. Some
writers have suggested that “that the propensity of … [net financial inflows] … to boost growth
must be regarded as a strictly short-run result … [and] … cannot represent the long-run
equilibrium growth rate” (Setterfield, 2011:408). However, that conclusion remains purely an
assertion. Why has Australia, for example, been able to run persistently large current account
deficits for extended periods of time without any observed collapse in the currency or any debt
crisis?
Belkar et al. (2007: 28) note that a nation can have ‘a number of institutional features that help
to lessen its vulnerability of external shocks’. They itemise these features: ‘Stable government,
credible and sustainable monetary and fiscal policies, a sound financial system based on
efficient regulation and supervision, effective legal and accounting frameworks, and
transparent and open markets for factors of production and outputs’ (p. 29). These features
allow a nation ‘to be resilient in the face of large nominal exchange rate fluctuations’ and
provide an attractive basis for attracting a stable volume of capital inflows.
Palumbo (2009: 363) also notes that later in his career, Kaldor (1989) effectively abandoned
his earlier position ‘as he applies the model to the analysis of actual processes of growth in real
economies’. Post Keynesians who consider the BPCG concept to be an eternal verity and a
major flaw in MMT appear to have lost sight of Kaldor’s shift.
Another curious aspect of the popularity of Thirlwall’s law is the adherence to a long-run
equilibrium separate from the short-run. Neoclassical theory has always considered such a
distinction to be significant and the temporal separation into short-run periods and some
distinct long-run period has been used to attack policy-activism by government. However,
Kalecki, among others clearly rejected this temporal dichotomy. King (2002: 54) in
summarising Kalecki’s approach, wrote that one characteristic was:
There is no such thing as the long run, defined independently of the set of short periods
which constitute it. The notion that neoclassical equilibrium analysis applies in such a
long run is profoundly mistaken.
6.Additional considerations with respect to the BPCG theory
6.1, Flexible exchange rates and inflation
BPCG theory leads to conclusion that if the markets ‘sell-off’ a currency, the increase in import
prices and resulting inflation will negate any real income gains that might be made through
domestic expansionary policy. Clearly, exchange rate movements influence real value of the
nominal incomes produced. Non-tradable goods and services will be much less influenced by
exchange rate movements than direct imports. In many cases, these goods and services will
have negligible exposure to exchange rate movements. The provision of many services, for
example, will have little variability to exchange rate fluctuations.
The extent to which movements in domestic prices are influenced by shifts in import prices
arising from exchange rate movements depends on the degree of ‘pass through’ and the
importance of imported goods and services to the overall basket that determines the workers’
material living standards.
The estimates of ‘exchange rate pass through’ (ERPT) are highly variable and depend on many
factors including the extent of the exchange rate shift, how much spare capacity there is in the
economy, the adjustment costs incurred to adjust prices, the degree of import competition, etc.
(see for example, Taylor, 2000).
The sensitivity of domestic inflation to changes in import prices is also important. ERPT might
be high and rapid but this sensitivity might be low and drawn out, making the overall impact
inconsequential. There is also the question of time lags and the sum of the two impacts can
take years to manifest.
While it is difficult to statistically disentangle these separate effects, Bailliu et al. (2010: 1)
conclude that ‘a substantial literature has shown that the correlation between changes in
consumer prices and changes in the nominal exchange rate has been quite low and declining
over the past two decades for a broad group of countries’ (see also Parker, 2014; Forbes, 2015).
Forbes (2015) concluded that:
First, contrary to common belief, exchange rate movements don’t seem to consistently
have larger effects on prices in sectors with a higher share of imported content. Second,
exchange rates don’t seem to consistently have larger effects on prices in the most
tradable and internationally-competitive sectors. Third, the effects of exchange rates on
inflation – and even just on import prices – do not seem to be consistent across time.
Most of what I learned in grad school on this topic no longer seems to apply.
6.2 Living beyond the nation’s means
Proponents of the BPCG theory construct trade deficits as signalling a nation ‘living beyond
its means’. The excess of investment over saving can only be countered with the net
accumulation of foreign claims on the nation. The proponents of this view then claim that the
nation’s potential growth path is lowered because local profit retention and hence local
investment is reduced.
There are several issues. From a consumption perspective, it is undeniable that for an economy,
imports represent a real benefit while exports are a real cost. Thus, net imports means that a
nation gets to enjoy a higher material living standard by consuming more goods and services
than it produces for foreign consumption. Recognising this, does not mean we should disregard
a current account deficit.
First, it is true that foreigners (surplus nations) build up financial claims in the currency of the
deficit nation. If the government allowed, they might liquidate these claims purchasing real
estate (for example, Russian and Chinese property acquisitions in London), which might
undermine the prosperity of the local residents (for example, through housing affordability
issues). But the nation state can legislate whatever restrictions they like in this regard and
prevent foreigners purchasing strategic assets.
Second, the foreigners might liquidate their local currency holdings in forex markets. The
reason that nations can run external deficits is because foreigners are willing to exchange their
exports for financial claims in the local currency. That preference could change at any time.
Clearly, the deficit nation gains the terms of trade benefit while the preference holds. But if the
preference changed suddenly, then the deficit nation may be exposed to rather harsh adjustment
costs. That possibility should always be recognised. But major sell-offs of currency holders
would also expose the selling parties to exchange losses if a significant exchange rate
depreciation resulted.
Third, if the local currency holdings end up in the hands of speculators, which implies the
motivation is different from a trading entity, the nation state can always impose capital controls
to protect its currency (see Section 6.4)
Fourth, more problematic is that foreign interests may seek to use their financial clout to
manipulate the political system and the public through media domination. However, strict
campaign funding and media ownership rules can militate against these negative consequences.
6.3 Trade deficits and deindustrialisation
Some argue that persistent external deficits accelerate the process of deindustrialisation (loss
of manufacturing capacity), which reduces opportunities for high-skilled, well-paid
employment, damages productivity growth and innovation, and leaves the nation reliant on
imported goods and services. There are often arguments made that a nation needs to protect
local manufacturing to ensure self-reliance in the event of war. Which means that a government
can always adopt a forward-thinking industry policy to expand domestic industry, spawn
innovating research and development, upskill the workforce, build export capacity, etc, as long
it has available real resources or can acquire them from abroad. An MMT understanding allows
us to appreciate that there would be no financial impediment for a government building national
industries, funding research and development, providing first-class universities and
apprenticeship training and the rest. If a nation with its own currency slides into oblivion by
closing its manufacturing sector, cutting career public sector jobs and relying on low-paid and
precarious service sector jobs for employment creation, then that has little to do with running
external deficits, and everything to do with political choices.
Further, there are other reasons for maintaining a manufacturing sector, which include
maintaining infrastructure as part of a defence strategy and building self-sufficiency in essential
goods and services (such as health care products).
6.4 The role of capital controls
The BPCG literature suggests that governments must prioritise the appeasement of
international investors over domestic policy goals such as full employment. Clearly under
Bretton Woods, damaging speculative attacks on national currencies was a factor because the
speculators knew that in the short-run, the central bank would try to stabilise the currency at
the agreed parity and as a result, the short-sellers could reap havoc. As a result, governments
imposed recessed conditions on their populace from time to time to head-off speculative
attacks.
The MMT position is that ultimately speculative financial flows not directly relating to
reducing exchange rate risk in real productive activities should be outlawed. But in lieu of that
being achieved through global cooperation, other means must be found by governments to
defend their currencies in the event of a speculative attack.
Capital controls have proven to be an effective strategy to restrict the free movement of capital
across borders in either direction. Mitchell (2023) discusses the types and uses of capital
controls in detail.
(Ikus Capital controls – William Mitchell – Modern Monetary Theory)
While there are various forms of controls that can be imposed, the important point is that they
free the central bank from directing monetary policy towards defending the nation’s currency
parity and allow the fiscal authorities to pursue demand management policies, which prioritise
domestic targets, such as full employment.
While mainstream economists claim that the financial markets will always subvert capital
controls, Rodrik (2010) notes that:
Even if true, evading the controls requires incurring additional costs to move funds in
and out of a country – which is precisely what the controls aim to achieve. Otherwise,
why would investors and speculators cry bloody murder whenever capital controls are
mentioned as a possibility? If they really couldn’t care less, then they shouldn’t care at
all.
The balance of payments should not be an issue of concern for governments when designing
policies to advance the well-being of their citizens. All open economies experience fluctuations
in their external balances. While these fluctuations were problematic under fixed exchange
rates, the exchange rate does the adjustment under a flexible system. There is no balance of
payments constraint facing a nation in this regard.
6.5 The plight of poor nations and industry policy
Noting that a currency-issuing government is not constrained in its capacity to generate full
employment through appropriate fiscal policy settings is not the same thing as saying that
achieving this desirable goal can rescue nation from poverty. The fact that such a government
can spend its own currency to bring idle resources back into productive use does not mean that
it can avoid the external factors that can constrain material prosperity. A currency-issuing
government in a poorer nation, particularly one that is dependent on imported food and energy,
faces additional constraints that cannot be easily solved with increased fiscal deficits.
But this insight just reinforces the initial observation that the ultimate constraint on material
prosperity is the real resources a nation can command (people, productive capital, and natural
resources). The reality is that if a nation that is dependent on imported food and/or energy,
cannot find sufficient demand for its exports, then the capacity of the currency-issuing
government to alleviate poverty is limited. While this might appear to be a ‘balance of
payments constraint’, it is better conceived as a real resource constraint arising from spatial
inequalities in the unequal distribution of resources.
MMT considers the only effective way to resolve real resource constraints that operate through
the balance of payments is for all nations to share responsibilities mediated through a new
multilateral institution that would replace the failed World Bank and IMF. Such an organisation
would be required to ensure that disadvantaged nations would have access to essential real
resources at fair terms (see Mitchell and Fazi, 2017).
Further policy initiatives would be required including: (a) outlawing speculation in financial
markets on food and other essential commodities; (b) multilateral agreements to end financial
market speculation that has no necessary relationship with improving the operation of the real
economy; (c) use of import controls on luxury items that only the rich enjoy would provide
more external space to import essentials; rewarding nations that restrict their own capacity to
export commodities that are injurious to global well-being (such as coal).
This discussion also feeds into the need for industry policy, given the problem facing less
developed nations is the lack of a stable industrial base. Nations that trade in industrial goods
enjoy more stable prices in international markets than primary commodity exporters, who
endure large swings in their terms of trade, which make it difficult build viable manufacturing
sectors (Corden and Neary, 1982). Mitchell (2023) argues that nations that chose a state-driven
import-substitution approach to industrialisation grew strongly without an export-bias. Further,
the reason that growth was not sustained in the 1970s is because the IMF and World Bank
forced nations into abandoning import-substitution strategies in return for currency support,
not that such strategies failed. Import-substitution strategies increase self-reliance and allow a
nation to better avoid the damage from fluctuations driven by currency speculation (see also,
Rowthorn, 1981; Chang, 2007; and Cherif and Hasanov, 2019).
References
Bailliu, J., Dong, W. and Murray, J. (2010) ‘Has Exchange Rate Pass-Through Really
Declined? Some Recent Insights from the Literature’, Bank of Canada Review, Autumn 2010,
1-8.
Belkar, R., Cockerell, L., and Kent, C. (2007) ‘Current Account Deficits: The Australian
Debate’, Reserve Bank of Australia Research Discussion Paper 2007-02, March.
Chang, Ha-Joon (2007) Bad Samaritans: The Myth of Free Trade and the Secret History of
Capitalism, London, Bloomsbury Press.
Cherif, R. and Hasanov, F. (2019) ‘The Return of the Policy That Shall Not Be Named:
Principles of Industrial Policy’, IMF Working Paper 19/74, International Monetary Fund,
Washington.
Corden, W.M. and Neary, J.P. (1982) ‘Booming Sector and De-industrialisation in a Small
Open Economy’, The Economic Journal, 92, 825–48.
Epstein, G. (2020) ‘The Empirical and Institutional Limits of Modern Monetary Theory’,
Review of Radical Political Economics, 52(4), 772-780.
Forbes, K. (2015) ‘Much ado about something important: How do exchange rate movements
affect inflation?’, Speech at 47th Money, Macro and Finance Research Group Conference,
Cardiff.
Hicks, J.R. (1950) A Contribution to the Theory of the Trade Cycle, Oxford, Clarendon Press.
Hood, C. and Himaz, R. (2017) A Century of Fiscal Squeeze Politics: 100 Years of Austerity,
Politics, and Bureaucracy in Britain, Oxford, Oxford University Press.
Johnson, H.G. (1969) ‘The Case For Flexible Exchange Rates’, The Federal Reserve Bank of
St. Louis Review, June, 12-24.
Kaldor, N. (1957) ‘A Model of Economic Growth’, The Economic Journal, 67(268),
December, 591-624.
Kaldor, N. (1970) ‘The case for regional policies’, Scottish Journal of Political Economy,
17(3), November, 337-48.
Kaldor, N. (1971) ‘Conflicts in national economic objectives’, The Economic Journal, 81(321),
March, 1–16.
Kaldor, N. (1978) Further Essays on Economic Theory, London, Duckworth.
Kaldor, N. (1989) ‘The role of effective demand in the short and long–run growth’, in A.
Barrére (org.), The Foundations of Keynesian Analysis, London, Macmillan Press, 1988.
King, J.E. (2002) A history of Post Keynesian economics since 1936, Cheltenham, Edward
Elgar.
McCombie, J.S.L. (2011) ‘Criticisms and defences of the balance-of-payments constrained
growth model: some old, some new’, PSL Quarterly Review, 64(259), 353-392.
McCombie, J.S.L. and Roberts, M. (2002) ‘The Role of the Balance of Payments in Economic
Growth’, in Setterfield, M. (ed.) The Economics of Demand-Led Growth: Challenging the
Supply-Side Vision of the Long Run, Cheltenham, Edward Elgar, 87-114.
McCombie, J.S.L. and Thirwall, A.P. (1994) Economic Growth and the Balance-of-Payments
Constraint, London, Macmillan.
Mitchell, W.F. (2015) Eurozone Dystopia: Groupthink and Denial on a Grand Scale,
Cheltenham, Edward Elgar.
Mitchell, W.F. (2023) ‘The Balance of Payments and Modern Monetary Theory’, in Wray,
L.R., Armstrong, P., Holland, S., Jackson-Prior, C., Plumridge, P. and Wilson, N. (eds.)
Modern Monetary Theory: Key Insights, Leading Thinkers, Cheltenham, Edward Elgar,
forthcoming.
Mitchell, W.F. and Fazi, T. (2017) Reclaiming the State: A Progressive Vision of Sovereignty
for a Post-Neoliberal World, London, Pluto Books.
Mitchell, W.F., Wray, L.R. and Watts, M.J. (2019) Macroeconomics, London, Red Globe
Press.
Okun, A.M. (1981) Prices and Quantities: A Macroeconomic Analysis, Washington, D.C., The
Brookings Institute.
Palumbo, A. (2009) ‘Adjusting Theory to Reality: The Role of Aggregate Demand in Kaldor’s
Late Contributions on Economic Growth’, Review of Political Economy, 21(3), 341-368.
Parker, M. (2014) ‘Exchange rate movements and consumer prices: some perspectives’,
Reserve Bank of New Zealand Bulletin, 77(1), 31-41.
Robinson, J. (1947) Essays in the Theory of Employment, Oxford, Basil Blackwell.
Rodrik, D. (2010) ‘The End of an Era in Finance’, Project Syndicate, March 11, 2010.
Rowthorn, R. (1981) ‘The Politics of the Alternative Economic Strategy’, Marxism Today,
January, 4-10.
Setterfield, M. (2011) ‘The remarkable durability of Thirlwall’s Law’, PSL Quarterly Review,
64(259), 393-427.
Taylor, J. (2000) ‘Low Inflation, Pass-Through, and Pricing Power of Firms’, European
Economic Review, 44(7), 1389–408.
Thirlwall, A.P. (1979) ‘The Balance of Payments Constraint as an Explanation of International
Growth Rate Differences’, Banca Nazionale del Lavoro Quarterly Review, March, 32, 45-53.